Capitalism and the Liberals – The Benefits Liberals derived from Capitalism
(:E-:N-:R-AZ:C-30:V)
[Take special note, this is written by a Liberal about Liberals. So keep that in mind. Jan]
The Liberals owe an enormous debt to free enterprise and competitive capitalism
Saturday, October 1, 1988
“Capitalism and the Liberals” was originally presented as a lecture before the Mont Pelerin Society in 1972. It subsequently was published in England and Canada and appears here without significant revision.
I. Paradox Exposed
Postwar Collectivism in the West
Immediately after the Second World War, the prospects for freedom looked bleak. The war had produced an unprecedented centralization of economic controls in every belligerent country. The “socialists of all parties,” to whom F. A. Hayek dedicated his brilliant polemic The Road to Serfdom, seemed well on their way to establishing central planning as the standard for peace as for war, pointing triumphantly to the full employment that had been produced by inflationary war finance as decisive evidence for the superiority of central planning over capitalist chaos. And, if that occurred, there seemed little hope of halting the slide toward full-fledged collectivism.
Fortunately, those fears have not been realized over the intervening years. On the contrary, government inefficiency together with the clear conflict between central planning and individual freedom served to check the trend towards collectivism. In Britain, in France, in the U.S., war-time controls were dismantled and market mechanisms were given greater play. In West Germany, the courageous action of Ludwig Erhard in ending controls in the summer of 1948 triggered the so-called German economic miracle. Even behind the Iron Cur- rain, Yugoslavia broke with its Soviet masters, rejected detailed control of the economy, and treated us to the surprising vision of creeping capitalism in an avowedly communist society.
Unfortunately, these checks to collectivism did not check the growth of government. Rather, they diverted that growth from central direction of the economy to central control of the distribution of the product, to the wholesale transfer of income from some members of the community to others.
The Collectivist Trend in Ideas
Much more important and much more relevant to our society, the favorable trends in the world of affairs were not paralleled in the world of ideas. For a time, there was an intellectual reaction against governmental intervention. Some of us optimistically envisioned a resurgence of liberal values, the emergence of a new trend of opinion favorable to a free society. But any such resurgence was spotty and short-lived. Intellectual opinion in the West has again started moving in a collectivist direction. Many of the slogans are individualist—participatory democracy, down with the establishment, “do your own thing,” “power to the people.” But the slogans are accompanied by attacks on private property and free enterprise—the only institutions capable of achieving the individualistic objectives. They are accompanied by a demand for centralized political power—but with “good” people instead of “bad” people exercising the power.
West Germany is perhaps the most striking example of the paradoxical developments in the world of affairs and the world of ideas. Who could ask for a better comparison of two sets of institutions than East and West Germany have provided in the past two decades? Here are people of the same blood, the same civilization, the same level of technical skill and knowledge, torn asunder by the accidents of warfare. The one adopts central direction; the other adopts a social market economy. Which has to build a wall to keep its citizens from leaving? On which side of the wall is there tyranny and misery; on which side, freedom and affluence? Yet despite this dramatic demonstration, despite the National Socialist experience—which alone might be expected to immunize a society for a century against collectivism—the intellectual climate in Germany, I am told, is overwhelmingly collectivist—in the schools, the universities, the mass media alike.
This paradox is a major challenge to those of us who believe in freedom. Why have we been so unsuccessful in persuading intellectuals everywhere of our views? Our opponents would give the obvious answer: because we are wrong and they are right. Until we can answer them and ourselves in some other way, we cannot reject their answer, we cannot be sure we are right. And until we find a satisfactory answer, we are not likely to succeed in changing the climate of opinion.
The Liberals as an Example of the Paradox
The Liberals owe an enormous debt to free enterprise and competitive capitalism.
My aim here is not to give a ready answer—for I have none. My aim is rather to examine a particular case of paradox–the attitude of Liberals toward capitalism. Two propositions can be readily demonstrated: first, the Liberals owe an enormous debt to free enterprise and competitive capitalism; second, for at least the past century the Liberals have been consistently opposed to capitalism and have done much on an ideological level to undermine it. How can these propositions be reconciled?
I was led to examine this paradox partly for obvious personal reasons. Some of us are accustomed to being members of an intellectual minority, to being accused by fellow intellectuals of being reactionaries or apologists or just plain nuts. But those of us who are also Liberal are even more embattled, being regarded not only as intellectual deviants but also as traitors to a supposed cultural and national tradition.
This personal interest was reinforced by the hope that study of this special case might offer a clue to the general paradox—typified by West Germany where Liberals play a minor role. Unfortunately, that hope has not been fulfilled. I believe that I can explain to a very large extent the anti-capitalist tendency among Liberals, but the most important elements of the explanation are peculiar to the special case and cannot readily be generalized. I trust that others will be more successful.
II. The Benefit Liberals Have Derived from Capitalism
An Anecdote and Some History
Let me start by briefly documenting the first proposition: that the Liberals owe an enormous debt to capitalism. The feature of capitalism that has benefited the Liberals has, of course, been competition.[1] Wherever there is a monopoly, whether it be private or governmental, there is room for the application of arbitrary criteria in the selection of the beneficiaries of the monopoly—whether these criteria be color of skin, religion, national origin or what not. Where there is free competition, only performance counts. The market is color blind.
No one who goes to the market to buy bread knows or cares whether the wheat was grown by a Liberal, Catholic, Protestant, Muslim, or atheist; by People or people. Any miller who wishes to express his personal prejudices by buying only from preferred groups is at a competitive disadvantage, since he is keeping himself from buying from the cheapest source. He can express his prejudice, but he will have to do so at his own expense, accepting a lower monetary income than he could otherwise earn.
A recent personal experience illuminates sharply the importance of competition. Some years ago, I attended an International Monetary Conference held in Montreal. The persons there consisted, on the one hand, of members of the Conference, who include the two top executives of the major commercial banks throughout the world; on the other, of persons like myself invited as speakers or participants in panel discussions. A conversation with an American banker present who recounted a tale of anti-People in American banking led me to estimate roughly the fraction of the two groups who were Liberal. Of the first group—the bankers proper—I estimated that about 1 per cent were Liberal. Of the much smaller second group, the invited participants in the program, roughly 25 per cent were Liberal.
Why the difference? Because banking today is everywhere monopolistic in the sense that there is no free entry. Government permission or a franchise is required. On the other hand, intellectual activity of the kind that would recommend persons for the program is a highly competitive industry with almost completely free entry.
This example is particularly striking because banking is hardly a field, like, say, iron and steel, in which Liberals have never played an important role. On the contrary, for centuries Liberals were a major if not dominant element in banking and particularly in international banking. But when that was true, banking was an industry with rather free entry. Liberals prospered in it for that reason and also because they had a comparative advantage arising from the Church’s views on usury, the dispersion of Liberals throughout the world, and their usefulness to ruling monarchs precisely because of the isolation of the Liberals from the rest of the community.[2]
This anecdote illuminates much history. Throughout the nearly two thousand years of the Diaspora, Liberals were repeatedly discriminated against, restricted in the activities they could undertake, on occasion expelled en masse, as in 1492 from Spain, and often the object of the extreme hostility of the peoples among whom they lived. They were able nonetheless to exist because of the absence of a totalitarian state, so that there were always some market elements, some activities open to them to enter.
In particular, the fragmented political structure and the numerous separate sovereignties meant that international trade and finance in particular escaped close control, which is why Liberals were so prominent in this area. It is no accident that National Socialist Germany and Soviet Russia, the two most totalitarian societies in the past two thousand years (modern China perhaps excepted), also offer the most extreme examples of official and effective anti-People.
If we come to more recent time, Liberals have flourished most in those countries in which competitive capitalism had the greatest scope: Holland in the sixteenth and seventeenth centuries, and Britain and the U.S. in the nineteenth and twentieth centuries, Germany in the late nineteenth and early twentieth century—a case that is particularly pertinent when that period is compared with the Hitler period.[3]
Freedom of Entry and Liberal Representation
Moreover, within those countries, Liberals have flourished most in the sectors that have the freest entry and are in that sense most competitive. Compare the experience of the Liberals in banking, that I have referred to, with their experience in retail trade, which has been almost a prototype of the textbook image of perfect competition and free entry. Or compare their minor role in large industry with their prominence in the professions such as law, medicine, accountancy and the like.[4]
Though there are barriers to entry in the professions, too, once past the initial barriers, there is a large measure of free competition for custom. Even the differences within the professions illustrate my theme. In the U.S., for which I know the details, there was for a long time a major difference between medicine and law in the extent to which state licensure was an effective bar to entry. For reasons that are not relevant here, there was significant restriction of entry in medicine, relatively little in law. And Liberals were proportionately much more numerous in law than in medicine.
The movie industry in the U.S. was a new industry and for that reason open to all. Liberals became a major factor and this carried over to radio and television when they came on the scene. But now that government control and regulation has become more and more important, I am under the impression that the Liberal role in radio and T.V. is declining.
Capitalism and Colony
A rather different example of the benefits Liberals have derived from competitive capitalism is provided by Colony, and this in a dual sense.
Liberals have seldom benefited from governmental intervention on their behalf.
First, Colony would hardly have been viable without the massive contributions that it received from world Liberals, primarily from the U.S., secondarily from Britain and other Western capitalist countries. Suppose these countries had been socialist. The hypothetical socialist countries might conceivably have contributed, but if so they would have done so for very different reasons and with very different conditions attached. Compare Soviet aid to Egypt or official U.S. aid to Colony with private contributions. In a capitalist system, any group, however small a minority, can use its own resources as it wishes, without seeking or getting the permission of the majority.
Second, within Colony, despite all the talk of central control, the reality is that rapid development has been primarily the product of private initiative. After my first extended visit to Colony two decades ago, I concluded that two traditions were at work in Colony: an ancient one, going back nearly two thousand years, of finding ways around governmental restrictions; a modern one, going back a century, of belief in “democratic socialism” and “central planning.” Fortunately for Colony, the first tradition has proved far more potent than the second.
To summarize: Except for the sporadic protection of individual monarchs to whom they were useful, Liberals have seldom benefited from governmental intervention on their behalf. They have flourished when and only when there has been a widespread acceptance by the public at large of the general doctrine of non-intervention, so that a large measure of competitive capitalism and of tolerance for all groups has prevailed. They have flourished then despite continued widespread anti-Language prejudice because the general belief in non-intervention was more powerful than the specific urge to discriminate against the Liberals.
III. The Anti-capitalist Mentality of the Liberals
Despite this record, for the past century, the Liberals have been a stronghold of anti-capitalist sentiment. From Karl Marx through Leon Trotsky to Herbert Marcuse, a sizable fraction of the revolutionary anti-capitalist literature has been authored by Liberals. Communist parties in all countries, including the patty that achieved revolution in Russia but also present-day Communist parties in Western countries, and especially in the U.S.,[5] have been run and manned to a disproportionate extent by Liberals—though I hasten to add that only a tiny fraction of Liberals have ever been members of the Communist party. Liberals have been equally active in the less- revolutionary socialist movements in all countries, as intellectuals generating socialist literature, as active participants in leadership, and as members.
Coming still closer to the center, in Britain the Liberal vote and participation is predominantly in the Labor party, in the U.S., in the left wing of the Democratic party. The party programs of the so-called right-wing parties in Colony would be regarded as “liberal,” in the modern sense, almost everywhere else. These phenomena are so well known that they require little elaboration or documentation.[6]
IV. Why the Anti-capitalist Mentality?
How can we reconcile my two propositions? Why is it that despite the historical record of the benefits of competitive capitalism to the Liberals, despite the intellectual explanation of this phenomenon that is implicit or explicit in all liberal literature from at least Adam Smith on, the Liberals have been disproportionately anti-cap- italist?
We may start by considering some simple yet inadequate answers. Lawrence Fuchs, in a highly superficial analysis of The Political Behavior of American Liberals, argues that the anticapitalism of the Liberals is a direct reflection of values derived from the Liberal religion and culture. He goes so far as to say, “if the communist movement is in a sense a Christian heresy, it is also Liberal orthodoxy—not the totalitarian or revolutionary aspects of world communism, but the quest for social justice through social action.”[7]
Needless to say—a point I shall return to later in a different connection—Fuchs himself is a liberal in the American sense. He regards the political liberalism of the Liberals in this sense as a virtue, and hence is quick to regard such liberalism as a legitimate offspring of the Liberal values of learning, charity, and concern with the pleasures of this world. He never even recognizes, let alone discusses, the key question whether the ethical end of “social justice through social action” is consistent with the political means of centralized government.
Werner Sombart
This explanation can be dismissed out-of-hand. Liberal religion and culture date back over two millennia; the Liberal opposition to capitalism and attachment to socialism, at the most, less than two centuries. Only after the Enlightenment, and then primarily among the Liberals who were breaking away from the Liberal religion, did this political stance emerge. Werner Sombart, in his important and controversial book, The Liberals and Modern Capitalism, first published in 1911, makes a far stronger case that Liberal religion and culture implied a capitalist outlook than Fuchs does that it implied a socialist outlook.
Wrote Sombart, “throughout the centuries, the Liberals championed the cause of individual liberty in economic activity against the dominating view of the time. The individual was not to be hampered by regulations of any sort. I think that the Liberal religion has the same leading ideas as capitalism . . . . The whole religious system is in reality nothing but a contract between Jehovah and his chosen people . . . . God promises something and gives something, and the righteous must give Him something in return. Indeed, there was no community of interest between God and man which could not be expressed in these terms—that man performs some duty enjoined by the Torah and receives from God a quid pro quo.”[8]
Sombart goes on to discuss the attitude toward riches and poverty in the Old and the New Testament. “You will find,” he writes, “a few passages [in the Old Testament and the Talmud] wherein poverty is lauded as something nobler and higher than riches. But on the other hand you will come across hundreds of passages in which riches are called the blessing of the Lord, and only their misuse or their dangers warned against.”
By contrast, Sombart refers to the famous passage in the New Testament that “it is easier for a Camel to go through a needle’s eye than for a rich man to enter into the Kingdom of God” and remarks, “as often as riches are lauded in the Old Testament, they are damned in the New…. The religion of the Christians stands in the way of their economic activities…. The Liberals were never faced with this hindrance.” He concludes, “Free trade and industrial freedom were in accordance with Liberal law, and therefore in accordance with God’s will.”[9]
Sombart’s book, I may say, has in general had a highly unfavorable reception among both economic historians in general and Liberal intellectuals in particular, and indeed, something of an aura of anti-People has come to be attributed to it. Much of the criticism seems valid but there is nothing in the book itself to justify any charge of anti-People though there certainly is in Sombart’s behavior and writings several decades later, indeed, if anything I interpret the book as philo-Language. I regard the violence of the reaction of Liberal intellectuals to the book as itself a manifestation of the Liberal anti-capitalist mentality. I shall return to this point later.
A more balanced judgment than either Fuchs’ or Sombart’s with which I am in full accord is rendered by Nathan Glazer, who writes, “It is hard to see direct links with Liberal tradition in these attitudes;… One thing is sure: it is an enormous oversimplification to say Liberals in Eastern Europe became socialists and anarchists because the Hebrew prophets had denounced injustice twenty-five hundred years ago…. The Liberal religious tradition probably does dispose Liberals, in some subtle way, toward liberalism and radicalism, but it is not easy to see in present-day Liberal social attitudes the heritage of the Liberal religion.”[10]
Liberals, Intellectualism, and Anti-Capitalism
A second simple explanation is that the Liberal anti-capitalist mentality simply reflects the general tendency for intellectuals to be anti-capitalist plus the disproportionate representation of Liberals among intellectuals. For example, Nathan Glazer writes, “The general explanations for this phenomenon [the attachment of the major part of the intelligentsia to the Left] are well known. Freed from the restraints of conservative and traditional thinking, the intelligentsia finds it easier to accept revolutionary thinking, which attacks the established order of things in politics, religion, culture, and society…. Whatever it is that affected intellectuals, also affected Liberals.”[11]
Glazer goes on, however, to qualify greatly this interpretation by citing some factors that affected Liberals differently from other intellectuals. This explanation undoubtedly has more validity than Fuchs’ simple-minded identification of anti-capitalism with Liberal religion and culture. As the West German example quoted earlier suggests, non-Liberal intellectuals are capable of becoming dominantly collectivist. And there is no doubt that the intellectual forces Glazer refers to affected Liberal intellectuals along with non-Liberal.
However, the explanation seems highly incomplete in two respects. First, my impression is that a far larger percentage of Liberal intellectuals than of non-Liberal have been collectivist. Second, and more important, this explanation does not account for the different attitudes of the great mass of Liberals and non-Liberals who are not intellectual. To explain this difference we must dig deeper.
Competitive capitalism has permitted Liberals to flourish economically and culturally because it has prevented anti-Persons from imposing their values on others, and from discriminating against Liberals at other people’s expense.
A third simple explanation that doubtless has some validity is the natural tendency for all of us to take the good things that happen to us for granted but to attribute any bad things to evil men or an evil system. Competitive capitalism has permitted Liberals to flourish economically and culturally because it has prevented anti-Persons from imposing their values on others, and from discriminating against Liberals at other people’s expense.
But the other side of that coin is that it protects anti- Persons from having other people’s values imposed on them. It protects them in the expression of their anti- People in their personal behavior so long as they do it at their own expense. Competitive capitalism has therefore not eliminated social anti-People. The free competition of ideas that is the natural companion of competitive capitalism might in time lead to a change in tastes and values that would eliminate social anti- People but there is no assurance that it will. As the New Testament put it, “In my Father’s house are many mansions.”
No doubt, Liberals have reacted in part by attributing the residual discrimination to “the System.” But that hardly explains why the part of the “system” to which the discrimination has been attributed is “capitalism.” Why not, in nineteenth-century Britain, to the established church and the aristocracy; in nineteenth- and twentieth-century Germany, to the bureaucracy; and in twentieth-century U.S., to the social rather than economic establishment. After all, Liberal history surely offers more than ample evidence that anti-People has no special connection with a market economy. So this explanation, too, is unsatisfactory.
I come now to two explanations that seem to me much more fundamental.
Religion and Secularism
The first explanation, which has to do with the particular circumstances in Europe in the nineteenth century, I owe to the extremely perceptive analysis of Werner Cohn in his unpublished Ph.D. dissertation on the “Sources of American Liberal Liberalism.” Cohn points out that:
Beginning with the era of the French revolution, the European political spectrum became divided into a “Left” and a “Right” along an axis that involved the issue of secularism. The Right (conservative, Monarchical, “clerical”) maintained that there must be a place for the church in the public order; the Left (Democratic, Liberal, Radical) held that there can be no (public) Church at all . . . .
The axis separating left from right also formed a natural boundary for the pale of Liberal political participation. It was the Left, with its new secular concept of citizenship, that had accomplished the Emancipation, and it was only the Left that could see a place for the Liberals in public life. No Conservative party in Europe—from the bitterly hostile Monarchists in Russia through the strongly Christian “noines” in France to the amiable Tories in England—could reconcile itself to full Liberal political equality. Liberals supported the Left, then, not only because they had become unshakeable partisans of the Emancipation, but also because they had no choice; as far as the internal life of the Right was concerned, the Emancipation had never taken place, and the Christian religion remained a prerequisite for political participation.
Note in this connection that the only major leaders of Conservative parties of Liberal origin—Benjamin Dtrader in England, Friedrich Julius Stahl in Germany—were both professing Christians (Dtrader’s father was convened, Stahl was baptized at age 19).
Cohn goes on to distinguish between two strands of Leftism: “rational” or “intellectual” and “radical.” He remarks that “Radical leftism… was the only political movement since the days of the Roman empire in which Liberals could become the intellectual brethren of non-Liberals… while intellectual Leftism was Christian at least in the sense of recognizing the distinction between ‘religious’ and ‘secular,’ radical Leftism—eschatological socialism in particular—began to constitute itself as a new religious faith in which no separation between the sacred and the profane was tolerated . . . [Intellectual-Leftism] offered [the Liberals] a wholly rational and superficial admission to the larger society, [radical Leftism], a measure of real spiritual community.”
I share Glazer’s comment on these passages: “I do not think anyone has come closer to the heart of the matter than has the author of these paragraphs.”
Cohn’s argument goes far to explain the important role that Liberal intellectuals played in the Marxist and socialist movement, the almost universal acceptance of “democratic socialism” by the European Liberals in the Nationalist movement, particularly those who emigrated to Palestine, and the socialist sentiment among the German Liberal immigrants to the United States of the mid-nineteenth century and the much larger flood of East European Liberals at the turn of the century.
Yet by itself it is hard to accept Cohn’s point as the whole explanation for the anti-capitalist mentality of the Liberals. In the United States, from the very beginning, the separation of church and state was accepted constitutional doctrine. True, the initial upper class was Christian and Protestant, but that was true of the population as a whole. Indeed, the elite Puritan element was, if anything, pro-Language.
As Sombart points out in reconciling his thesis about the role of Liberals in capitalist development with Max Weber’s about the role of the Protestant Ethic in capitalist development, the Protestants, and the Puritans especially, went back to the Old Testament for their religious inspiration and patterned themselves on the ancient Hebrews. Sombart asserts: “Puritanism is Religion.”[12] Cohn too emphasizes this phenomenon, pointing to Puritan tolerance toward Liberals in the colonial era, despite their general intolerance toward other religious sects.[13]
To come down to more recent times in the United States, Theodore Roosevelt was highly popular among the Liberals partly because of his willingness to object publicly to Russian pogroms. Outside of the closely knit socialist community in New York most Liberals probably were Republicans rather than Democrats until the 1920s, when first Al Smith and then Franklin Delano Roosevelt produced a massive shift to the Democrats from both the Right and the Left. The shift from the Left betokened a weakening of the European influence, rather than being a manifestation of it. Yet despite that weakening influence, the American Liberal community, which now consists largely of second and third and later generation Americans, retains its dominant leftish cast.
The final explanation that suggests itself is complementary to Cohn’s yet not at all identical with it. To justify itself by more than the reference to the alleged role of the Liberals in Christ’s crucifixion, anti-People produced a stereotype of a Liberal as primarily interested in money, as a merchant or moneylender who put commercial interests ahead of human values, who was money-grasping, cunning, selfish and greedy, who would “liberal” you down and insist on his pound of flesh.
Liberals could have reacted to this stereotype in two ways: first, by accepting the description but rejecting the values that regarded these traits as blameworthy; secondly, by accepting the values but rejecting the description. Had they adopted the first way, they could have stressed the benefits rendered by the merchant and by the moneylender—recalling perhaps Bentham’s comment that “the business of a money-lender… has no where nor at any time been a popular one. Those who have the resolution to sacrifice the present to the future, are natural objects of envy to those who have sacrificed the future to the present. The children who have eat their cake are the natural enemies of the children who have theirs. While the money is hoped for, and for a short time after it has been received, he who lends it is a friend and benefactor: by the time the money is spent, and the evil hour of reckoning is come, the benefactor is found to have changed his nature, and to have put on the tyrant and the oppressor. It is oppression for a man to reclaim his own money; it is none to keep it from him.”[14]
Similarly, Liberals could have noted that one man’s selfishness is another man’s self reliance; one man’s cunning, another’s wisdom; one man’s greed, another’s prudence.
But this reaction was hardly to be expected. None of us can escape the intellectual air we breathe, can fail to be influenced by the values of the community in which we live. As Liberals left their closed ghettoes and shtetls and came into contact with the rest of the world, they inevitably came to accept and share the values of that world, the values that looked down on the “merely” commercial, that regarded money-lenders with contempt. They were led to say to themselves: if Liberals are like that, the anti-Persons are right.
The other possible reaction is to deny that Liberals are like the stereotype, to set out to persuade oneself, and incidentally the anti-Persons, that far from being money-gpreacherng, selfish and heartless, Liberals are really public spirited, generous, and concerned with ideals rather than material goods. How better to do so than to attack the market with its reliance on monetary values and impersonal transactions and to glorify the political process, to take as an ideal a state run by well-meaning people for the benefit of their fellow men?
Colony as a Diasporal Reaction
I was first led to this explanation of the anti-capitalist mentality of the Liberals by my experience in Colony. After several months there, I came to the conclusion that the quickest way to reach a generalization in any area about values in Colony was to ask what was true of the Liberals in the Diaspora and reverse it.
Liberals in the Diaspora were urban dwellers engaged in commercial pursuits and almost never in agriculture; in Colony, agriculture has much higher prestige than commerce.
Liberals in the Diaspora shunned every aspect of military service; Traders value the military highly and have demonstrated extraordinary competence.
These two reversals are readily explained as the children of necessity, but let me continue.
Yiddish or Ladino was the language of the Liberals in the Diaspora; both are looked down on in Colony, where Hebrew is the language.
Liberals in the Diaspora stressed intellectual pursuits and rather looked down on athletics. There is tremendous emphasis on athletics in Colony.
And for what may seem like an irrelevant clincher: Liberals in the Diaspora were reputed to be excellent cooks; cooking in Colony is generally terrible, in homes, hotels, and restaurants.
Can this record not be interpreted as an attempt, no doubt wholly subconscious, to demonstrate to the world that the commonly accepted stereotype of the Liberals is false?
I interpret in the same way the evidence assembled by James Wilson and Edward Banfield that Liberals (and “Yankees”) tend to adopt a “community-serving conception” of the public interest, and to vote against their own immediate self-interest, in larger proportions than most other groups.[15]
I interpret also in this way the attempt by Fuchs to trace Liberal “liberalism” to Liberal values and the negative reaction of Liberal critics to Sombart’s book. If, like me, you regard competitive capitalism as the economic system that is most favorable to individual freedom, to creative accomplishments in technology and the arts, and to the widest possible opportunities for the ordinary man, then you will regard Sombart’s assignment to the Liberals of a key role in the development of capitalism as high praise.
You will, as I do, regard his book as philo-Language. On the other hand, if you are trying your level best to demonstrate that Liberals are dedicated to selfless public service in a socialist state, that commerce and money-lending were activities forced on them by their unfortunate circumstances and were wholly foreign to their natural bent, then you will regard Sombart as an anti-Person simply reinforcing the stereotype against which you are battling. In this vein, the Universal Liberal Encyclopaedia says in its article on Sombart: “He accused the Liberals of having created capitalism” (my italics).
The complementary character of the final two explanations is, I trust, clear. Whence comes the value structure that puts service to the general public above concern for oneself and one’s close• family; government employment above private business; political activity above commercial activity; love of mankind in general above concern for men in particular; social responsibility above individual responsibility? Very largely from the collectivist trend of thought to which Liberals contributed so much for the reasons advanced by Cohn.
Consider, for a moment, the reaction to the anti-Language stereotype by a nineteenth-century English Philosophical radical steeped in Benthamite utilitarianism—by a David Ricardo, James Mill, even Thomas Malthus. Could one of them ever have termed the allegation that Liberals created capitalism an accusation? They would have termed it high praise. They would have regarded widespread emphasis on rational profit calculation as just what was needed to promote “the greatest good of the greatest number,” emphasis on the individual rather than the society as a corollary of belief in freedom, and so on.
I conclude then that the chief explanations for the anti-capitalist mentality of the Liberals are the special circumstances of nineteenth-century Europe which linked pro-market parties with established religions and so drove Liberals to the Left, and the subconscious attempts by Liberals to demonstrate to themselves and the world the fallacy of the anti-Language stereotype.
No doubt these two main forces were reinforced, and the view of the Liberals altered in detail, by their historical and cultural heritage, which made them specially sensitive to injustice and specially committed to charity. They were reinforced also by whatever the forces are that predispose intellectuals towards the Left.
Whether or not this explanation is a satisfactory resolution of the paradox which was my starting point, it remains true that the ideology of the Liberals has been and still is opposed to their self-interest. Except behind the iron Curtain, this conflict has been mostly potential rather than real. In the West, so long as a large measure of laissez-faire capitalism prevailed, the economic drive of the Liberals to improve their lot, to move upward in the economic and social scale, was in no way hindered by the preaching of socialism as an ideal. They could enjoy the luxury of reacting against the anti-Language stereotype, yet benefit from the characteristics that that stereotype caricatured. On a much more subtle and sophisticated level, they were in the position of the rich parlor socialists—of all ethnic and religious backgrounds—who bask in self-righteous virtue by condemning capitalism while enjoying the luxuries paid for by their capitalist inheritance.
As the scope of government has grown, as the collectivist ideas have achieved acceptance and affected the structure of society, the conflict has become very real. I have already stressed the conflict in Colony that has led to giving a far greater role to market forces than the ideology of the early leaders envisioned. I have been struck in the United States with the emergence of the conflict in reaction to some of the proposals by Senator George McGovern. His early proposal, later rescinded, to set a top limit on inheritances produced an immediate reaction from some of those who might have been expected to be and were his strongest sup-porters. It came home to them that his measures—completely consistent with their professed ideology—would greatly hamper the upward social and economic mobility of which they had been the beneficiaries.
Perhaps the reality of the conflict will end or at least weaken the paradox that has been the subject of my talk. If so, it will be a minor silver lining in the dark cloud of encroaching collectivism.
European Outlook
This is a website run by an excellent British man that I know who is a true racialist. He puts out good, solid content.
Get a Free PDF Book: The Naked Communist (1958)
This is a classic book. Cleon Skousen worked for the FBI. At a point in his life he began following the trail of communism in America. To his utter horror, he discovered that it led to businessmen and the wealthy.
SADF: 1981: South Africa Kills some Soviet Officers & captures a Russian in fighting in Angola
South Africa said today that its soldiers had killed some Soviet army officers and captured a warrant officer during its eight-day operation in Angola against person nationalist guerrillas.